Waiting
Login processing...

Trial ends in Request Full Access Tell Your Colleague About Jove
JoVE Science Education
Cognitive Psychology

A subscription to JoVE is required to view this content.

 

Prospect Theory

Overview

Source: Laboratory of Jonathan Flombaum—Johns Hopkins University

What’s the value of a dollar? Currencies store value to facilitate trade. Implied in any economic transaction is the value of a unit of currency. But what is the subjective value of a dollar? For a long time, economists assumed the answer to this question to be, specifically, that a dollar has a value determined by the market and that the subjective value of a dollar is always that, more or less.

Beginning in the early 1970s, experimental psychologists Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky upended this assumption, showing that the subjective value of currency depends on a number of factors, most notably, whether losses or gains are being discussed, and the overall size of a transaction. To pump intuition, consider the fact that, to most people, it would seem reasonable to drive an extra half-mile in order to save $2 on a gallon of gas. But very few people would do the same to save $2 on the cost of a new car. So $2 is sometimes, but not always worth an extra half-mile drive. Value is context-dependent.

The theory devised by Kahneman and Tversky to describe how people psychologically value currency (and goods and services, generally) is called Prospect Theory. In 2002, Kahneman was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics for Prospect Theory, along with related research using the methods and theories of experimental psychology to understand economic decision-making (Tversky passed away in 1996.).

Many of the primary implications of Prospect Theory were obtained through survey experiments. The surveys consisted of choices between gambles; for example, subjects might be asked whether they would prefer to receive $5 or risk receiving nothing with a 50% chance of winning $10.

This video will demonstrate procedures for designing the type of survey questions used in research on Prospect Theory.

Procedure

1. Stimulus design

  1. When options have known outcomes and probabilities, economists describe the value of each choice as the average of its outcomes weighted by their respective probabilities, what they call a choice’s expected value.
  2. For example, a guaranteed win of $5 has an expected value of $5, and a gamble that pays out $10, 50% of the time (and nothing the other 50% of the time) also has an expected value of $5: 0.5 x 0 + 0.5 x 10 = 5.
  3. Devise gambles that tend to lead to different decisions, despite similar or equal expected values (Figure 1), in order to design a proper survey to study Prospect Theory.
    Figure 1
    Figure 1. Two gambles consisting of choices with equal expected value ($5) as either gains (1) or losses (2). In gamble 1, the expected value of both choices is a gain of $5. In gamble 2, the expected value of both choices is a loss of $5. The choices in each gamble also have equivalent probabilities. Therefore, standard economic theory makes two predictions. First, whatever choice a person prefers in one of the gambles, they should prefer the same choice in the other gamble. A person willing to take a risk in order to win $5 should be willing to take an equivalent risk in order to avoid paying $5. And on average, over many participants, choices A and B should be picked equally often. But actual behavior does not conform to these predictions. Many more people will take the risk—choice B—in gamble 2 than would in gamble 1, because losses have greater subjective value than equivalent gains. This is called loss aversion.
  4. When choosing sample questions for a survey, look for situations with a clear favorite between choices with equal expected values, a preference for a choice with a lower expected value, and a difference when the scenario is applied to gains compared to losses. Also consider situations with very small probabilities and with very high ones (Table 1).
A B
[4000,1] [5000, .9]
[-4000,1] [-5000, .9]
[5,1] [10, .9]
[-5,1] [-10, .9]
[5000, .9] [10,000, .45]
[5000, .04] [10,000, .02]

Table 1. The first number in each bracket denotes a currency value, and the second denotes the probability associated with that outcome.

2. Procedure

  1. Once a survey is created, give it to a large group of participants (between 50 and 100 people).
  2. If one intends the results to be published or shared publicly in other ways, acquire the necessary human ethics approval and informed consent.
  3. Create a cover page that informs the participant that their responses are anonymous and that they can choose not to complete the survey, and include a place for them to sign to indicate consent.
  4. After the survey is given to an appropriate number of participants, tally up the number who chose each option—A and B—for each question.
  5. Compare preferences expressed in related questions to reveal the nature of subjective value with respect to risk, reward, and losses.

"Prospect Theory" was devised by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, beginning in the 1970s, as a way to describe how people psychologically value currency.

On one hand, any unit of currency-like the US dollar-has an objective value, determined by the market. If a person is preparing to travel abroad and exchanging currency, it is this objective value that will dictate how many euros they can expect to receive for fifty dollars.

However, currency can also have a subjective, psychological value, which a person "assigns" to it based on many different factors, including the size of the purchase they are considering and potential relative savings.

To elaborate, a person may be willing to drive an extra mile to save two dollars on every gallon of gas, but not to save the same amount on a new, $20,000 car. Thus, two dollars is sometimes-but not always-worth an extra mile trip.

Originally formulated using survey data, Prospect Theory provides researchers with a model to predict an individual's subjective perceptions of objective monetary gains or losses.

In this video, you will learn how to create survey questions to study Prospect Theory, collect and analyze participant data in the form of survey responses, and learn how these can provide insight into the psychological value people place on currency.

In this experiment, participants complete a survey with questions pertaining to gambles-theoretical events in which they could potentially lose or gain a sum of money.

In questions dealing with gains, a scenario is presented where the participant has already received money-like winning five dollars in a raffle.

The participant must then choose between two options as to what to do with the sum: either keep all of it, or risk it for a chance to win a higher amount.

Similarly, when a participant encounters a loss question, they must pick between options of paying a debt, or risking a greater loss for a chance to have the debt erased.

The trick here is that both options to a question have the same expected value-the average amount of money gained or lost over several trials-which takes into account the probability of a win or loss.

It's the manner in which these values are presented-either as "sure things" or "risks" with a lower probability of success-which allows for an assessment of the subjective, psychological value of currency.

Participants are presented with a variety of such questions in a survey, where the probabilities of gains or loses-as well as the actual monetary amounts at stake-vary.

Here, the dependent variable is the subjective value of currency, which is determined by calculating the percentage of participants that chose a particular option to a question.

Based on the previous work of Kahneman and Tversky, it is expected that participants will overestimate the subjective value of monetary losses, especially small ones, viewing them as worth more than their actual, objective values.

To begin, create a survey with roughly 20 questions, and include questions dealing with diverse loss and gain scenarios.

Verify that both options associated with each question demonstrate the same expected value, as well as a range of monetary values with risks associated with different probabilities.

Before distributing the survey to participants, generate a cover page to include with informed consent, which explains to participants that they do not have to complete the questions, and that their responses are anonymous. Make sure to include a signature line for participants to indicate their consent.

Once the survey is finalized, distribute it to between 50 and 100 randomly selected participants. Note that individuals can be tested in groups. Allow them 15 min to complete the 20 questions.

When the participants are done, collect the surveys.

To analyze the data, for every question calculate the percentage of participants that chose each option-either A or B.

Compare participant preferences in similar questions, such as those dealing with small sums of money either lost or won.

Notice that more participants will tend to take a risk to avoid a financial loss compared to an equivalent gain, meaning that a greater subjective value is placed on monetary losses.

Also notice that participants will be less likely to risk large sums in gain scenarios, indicating that their subjective value of monetary gains can decrease depending on the context.

Now that you've learned how to create surveys to study Prospect Theory, let's take a look at how experimental psychologists are using this theory to investigate aspects of decision-making behavior.

As surveys that assess Prospect Theory deal with monetary losses and gains, these studies can aid our understanding of the psychological underpinnings of gambling and gambling addiction.

Importantly, such work has allowed researchers to connect the high subjective value of monetary losses to the tendency to keep gambling even as debts mount.

Researchers can also pair automated variations of Prospect Theory surveys with technologies like functional MRI, which can identify "activated" brain regions. This helps scientists determine the neuroanatomical basis for how participants assign subjective values to monetary sums under different situations.

Finally, Prospect Theory can also be used to develop new marketing strategies, such as stores offering perceived discounts on lower-priced items, to which consumers would assign high subjective values.

You've just watched JoVE's video on Prospect Theory. By now, you should have an idea of how to design survey questions to investigate this phenomenon, collect and analyze participants' responses, and relate the Prospect Theory to human behaviors like gambling.

In addition, you should have a grasp of how the Prospect Theory relates to the subjective and objective values of currency, which are not always the same.

Thanks for watching!

Subscription Required. Please recommend JoVE to your librarian.

Results

There are several classic effects that arise in these surveys. Figure 1 illustrates one effect, sometimes known as loss aversion. People seem to place a greater subjective value on losses than on gains of equivalent value. For question 1, between 60-80% of participants will typically choose A, while the same proportion will choose B for question 2. A 50% gamble seems worth the risk to avoid a debt of $5, but not to earn an extra $5. $5 is subjectively more valuable when it is a loss.

Figure 2 illustrates two more typical effects, associated with certainty and large numbers. In question 1, the participant chooses between a guaranteed win of $10,000 or a 90% chance of winning $11,167. 90% is a good bet, and a payout of $11,167 gives that bet an expected value of $10,050. Still, almost no one picks the bet, revealing a baseline preference for certain outcomes. Question 2 sets up a very similar situation, but with much smaller numbers: a guaranteed win of $5 compared to a 0.9 chance of winning $67. Note that choice B produces an expected value of $55–$50 more than the guaranteed win. Here, a majority of participants choose B, forgoing a certain win for a chance to win an extra $50 (on average). But they don’t do the same with question 1. To an economist, $50 is worth $50. If a person takes a risk to win it in one place, they should do the same in another. But, psychologically, it turns out that $50 added to $10,000 is worth less than $50 added to $5.

Figure 2
Figure 2. Two gambles that demonstrate the effects of certainty and large numbers on subjective value. In (1), choice B has an expected value of $10,050, $50 more than the guaranteed win in choice A. Yet people overwhelmingly tend to choose A. In (2), the gamble in choice B again has an expected value that is $50 more than the certain outcome in choice A. But here, people overwhelmingly choose B. $50 in expected value seems worth the risk when it will be added to $5, but not when it will be added to $10,000. The subject value of $50 is smaller when it is framed in relation to a large number.

Based on hundreds of comparative gambles of this kind, in experiments spanning gains and losses, large and small numbers, and even using real (as opposed to hypothetical) payouts, Kahneman and Tversky developed the now famous and influential Prospect Theory curve (Figure 3). The curve relates subjective value to actual value in terms of gains and losses. Figure 4 emphasizes two main properties of the curve, rational subjective value placed on small gains—that is, small gains subjectively valued equivalently to their actual value—and an overestimation of small loses. Figure 5 emphasizes two more properties of the curve, diminishing subject value as actual value increases for already large gains or losses.

Figure 3
Figure 3. Based on their experiments, Kahneman and Tversky devised the descriptive Prospect Theory value function. The x-axis denotes the actual value of gains and losses, and the y-axis denotes the psychological value attributed subjectively.

Figure 4
Figure 4. Drawing a straight line through the origin helps to emphasize the ways that the Prospect Theory function deviates from what were previously the assumptions of economists. The straight line reflects a one-to-one correspondence between actual and subjective value. Small gains are valued appropriately. But small losses are overvalued subjectively.

Figure 5
Figure 5. Prospect Theory value function. Both large gains and losses are relatively undervalued.

Subscription Required. Please recommend JoVE to your librarian.

Applications and Summary

Prospect Theory has had wide ranging implications and applications. That is why Kahneman was ultimately awarded the Nobel Prize.

For example, Prospect Theory explains a lot of gambling behavior, such as the tendency of people to continue gambling when they have losses. Even small losses loom large, subjectively, and it makes people willing to take risks they would not normally take when given the prospect of erasing a loss. But this usually has the effect of producing larger and larger debts. As a result, Prospect Theory has implications for preventing pathological gambling.

It also has had an enormous impact on marketing. For example, it explains the effectiveness of “loss leaders.” Stores will often advertise relatively large discounts on cheaper items—$20 off before Christmas on an item that normally costs $40. The item may even sell at a loss, a negative profit margin for the store, but the hope is that the discount will be perceived as larger than it actually is, so consumers will subjectively value it as worth more than $20, owing to it being a discount. That will drive them to the store, where they might spend more on high margin and big-ticket items: TVs, stereos, and the like. Imagine if the store offered a $20 discount on a $2000 TV instead. Would anyone rush to that particular store?

Subscription Required. Please recommend JoVE to your librarian.

Transcript

Tags

Prospect Theory Daniel Kahneman Amos Tversky Psychological Value Of Currency Objective Value Subjective Value Currency Exchange Relative Savings Survey Data Model Prediction Subjective Perceptions Monetary Gains Monetary Losses Survey Questions Participant Data Analysis Psychological Value Of Currency Experiment Gambles

Get cutting-edge science videos from JoVE sent straight to your inbox every month.

Waiting X
Simple Hit Counter